• About
  • Adam Hengels
  • Emily Hamilton
  • Michael Lewyn
  • Salim Furth
  • What Should I Read to Understand Zoning?
  • Contact

Market Urbanism

Liberalizing cities | From the bottom up

“Market Urbanism” refers to the synthesis of classical liberal economics and ethics (market), with an appreciation of the urban way of life and its benefits to society (urbanism). We advocate for the emergence of bottom up solutions to urban issues, as opposed to ones imposed from the top down.

  • Email
  • Facebook
  • Linkedin
  • RSS
  • Twitter
  • Economics
  • housing
  • planning
  • Zoning
  • Urban[ism] Legends
  • Book Reviews

Matt Yglesias fails to make the right case against highways

November 12, 2008 By Stephen Smith

Matt Yglesias is one of the best mainstream bloggers on land use/transportation that I know of. As one blogger (who I don’t recall right now) once said, his urban planning and transportation posts could be blogs in their own right. However, it’s puzzling that in an article for Cato Unbound, he comes up with such a pathetic rejoinder to the O’Toole/Cox/Poole “vulgar libertarian” transportation cabal, who don’t seem to have ever met a road they didn’t like:

Or consider the fact that Randall [sic] O’Toole is indignant about the prospect of public expenditures on mass transit systems, but appears to have little to say about public funding of highways. This, too, looks more like a case of narrow business interests than sterling free market principles.

While Yglesias’ instincts are right – current transportation markets in America are highly distorted – the reason they’re distorted has little to do with the ways highways are financed. Based on some basic figures, Randal O’Toole concludes that the vast majority of road funding – over 80% – comes out of user fees. Now, of course there are still some subsidies there, but it’s really nothing compared to the subsidies that mass transit systems receive, which in America never even come close to covering operating costs, never mind capital expenditures. Now, there are some problems with the 80% number, such as the government’s favorable access to bond markets and the legacy of infrastructure that wasn’t paid for with user fees, but all in all, it’s hard to argue that roads have a subsidy advantage over mass transit.

However, that’s not to say that Yglesias doesn’t have a point when he says that libertarians and conservatives have blind spots when it comes to how they see transportation. But the real government benefit that the road/car system has over mass transit is density: there are innumerable regulations at every level of government in the United States which favor low-density, single-family detached housing over the denser forms that dominated non-rural areas before the 20th century. Successful roads as we have in America require this low density to remain (almost) financially solvent – it would be very difficult to cope with people’s road needs if they were allowed to build as densely as they would without maximum density zoning rules and minimum parking regulations.

As a thought experiment, imagine your local town/neighborhood with twice the density. Chances are, the roads would quickly become very congested. They would have to be widened, which would require money, and even more money than normal, because the government would have to purchase valuable land next to existing roads. (That is, assuming that eminent domain is not used.) The gas tax would have to be raised, and soon the costs would get out of hand. On the other hand, mass transit would become more profitable rather than less, because much less track needs to be laid to satisfy the same demand, and mass transit systems have much more excess capacity than roads. If densities are limited, though, then this alleviates both stress on roads that go through valuable urban property (which are expensive and difficult to widen) and forces people to drive farther, thus paying more in user fees.

There’s a legitimate case to be made against American transportation and land use policy, but condemning highway subsidies ain’t it.

This post was written by Stephen Smith, who writes for his own blog called Rationalitate.

Tweet

Filed Under: Free-market impostors, Transportation, Zoning Tagged With: free market urbanism, private transit, public transit, Randal O'Toole, Stephen Smith

About Stephen Smith

I graduated Spring 2010 from Georgetown undergrad, with an entirely unrelated and highly regrettable major that might have made a little more sense if I actually wanted to become an international trade lawyer, but which alas seems good for little else.

I still do most of the tweeting for Market Urbanism

Stephen had previously written on urbanism at Forbes.com. Articles Profile; Reason Magazine, and Next City

Comments

  1. Antiplanner says

    November 12, 2008 at 11:47 pm

    Those who say libertarians have blind spots when it comes to transportation are not reading what they say. People like Wendell Cox, Robert Poole, and yours truly are promoting more toll roads, seeking a phase out of gasoline taxes (which are a user fee but not a very good one), and oppose the use of sales taxes or other general funds for roads.

    We would be happy if all transportation were funded solely out of user fees. Would that mean more highways or more transit? We don’t know and we don’t care. If new highways pay for themselves, that’s an indication that we need more. If new transit can pay for itself, that’s an indication we need more.

    The idea, however, that there is some regulatory conspiracy forcing low-density development and that higher densities would “more profitable” (how can it be more profitable when it isn’t profitable today?) is a fantasy. There are few or no regulations regarding density in much of Texas, for example, and low density the lifestyle of choice for most of the people in Texas cities. Meanwhile, though transit is profitable in Hong Kong and parts of Japan. It loses huge amounts of money in Manhattan. If people didn’t drive to Manhattan and pay bridge tolls that are used to subsidize the subways, the transit system would fail tomorrow.

    Density isn’t the solution. Opening up transit systems to competition and encourage private operators to find innovative ways to provide transit will work better.

  2. Antiplanner says

    November 12, 2008 at 11:47 pm

    Those who say libertarians have blind spots when it comes to transportation are not reading what they say. People like Wendell Cox, Robert Poole, and yours truly are promoting more toll roads, seeking a phase out of gasoline taxes (which are a user fee but not a very good one), and oppose the use of sales taxes or other general funds for roads.

    We would be happy if all transportation were funded solely out of user fees. Would that mean more highways or more transit? We don’t know and we don’t care. If new highways pay for themselves, that’s an indication that we need more. If new transit can pay for itself, that’s an indication we need more.

    The idea, however, that there is some regulatory conspiracy forcing low-density development and that higher densities would “more profitable” (how can it be more profitable when it isn’t profitable today?) is a fantasy. There are few or no regulations regarding density in much of Texas, for example, and low density the lifestyle of choice for most of the people in Texas cities. Meanwhile, though transit is profitable in Hong Kong and parts of Japan. It loses huge amounts of money in Manhattan. If people didn’t drive to Manhattan and pay bridge tolls that are used to subsidize the subways, the transit system would fail tomorrow.

    Density isn’t the solution. Opening up transit systems to competition and encourage private operators to find innovative ways to provide transit will work better.

  3. Rationalitate says

    November 13, 2008 at 12:04 am

    The idea, however, that there is some regulatory conspiracy forcing low-density development and that higher densities would “more profitable” (how can it be more profitable when it isn’t profitable today?) is a fantasy.

    Real estate developers think otherwise. Jonathan Levine, in his book Zoned Out: Regulation, Markets, and Choices in Transportation and Metropolitan Land Use makes a very persuasive case that developers, at least, feel overwhelmingly that they are constricted from offering the densities that the market demands, precisely because of local and state regulations against building densely on one’s own property. There’s also evidence that he presents that points to consumers being unsatisfied with their choices of density, though those sorts of surveys are problematic because of the difference between consumers’ revealed preferences and their stated preferences.

    There are few or no regulations regarding density in much of Texas, for example, and low density the lifestyle of choice for most of the people in Texas cities.

    I presume you’re talking mostly about Houston, the so-called unzoned city. In that case, your statement that there are “few or no regulations regarding density” is false. As Michael Lewyn explains:

    Like other cities’ zoning codes, Houston’s municipal code creates auto dependency by artificially spreading out the population. Until 1999, the city required all single-family houses to gobble up 5,000 square feet of land. Although this limit is less rigid than minimum lot sizes in most suburbs, the city’s statute nevertheless insures that many residents will be unable to live within walking distance of a bus stop, which in turn means that those residents will be completely dependent on their cars. In 1999, the City Council partially deregulated density in neighborhoods closer to downtown. But since 98% of the city’s housing was built before 1999, this change in the law is of little importance.

    Houston’s parking regulations also create automobile dependency by encouraging driving and discouraging walking. Under Houston’s city code, virtually every structure in Houston must supply plenty of parking. For example, apartment buildings must have even more parking spaces than residents; landlords must supply 1.25 parking spaces for each efficiency apartment and 1.33 parking spaces for every bedroom. Offices, supermarkets, and other businesses are subject to similar restrictions. Such parking regulations discourage walking by forcing pedestrians to navigate through massive parking lots (and to dodge the vehicles driving them) to reach shops or jobs. And where walking is uncomfortable, most people will drive. In addition, minimum parking requirements, by taking land for parking that could have been used for housing or businesses, also reduce density, thus making the city less compact and more auto-dependent.

    Parking regulations, as explained by Donald Shoup in his book The High Cost of Free Parking are almost as important (if not more important) than zoning regulations in determining the density at which a developer can feasibly build.

    Density isn’t the solution.

    I’ll definitely agree with you that mandatory density isn’t the solution. However, liberalizing rules about how densely Americans can build (especially in cities and inner-suburbs) most definitely is part of the solution.

  4. rationalitate says

    November 13, 2008 at 12:04 am

    The idea, however, that there is some regulatory conspiracy forcing low-density development and that higher densities would “more profitable” (how can it be more profitable when it isn’t profitable today?) is a fantasy.

    Real estate developers think otherwise. Jonathan Levine, in his book Zoned Out: Regulation, Markets, and Choices in Transportation and Metropolitan Land Use makes a very persuasive case that developers, at least, feel overwhelmingly that they are constricted from offering the densities that the market demands, precisely because of local and state regulations against building densely on one’s own property. There’s also evidence that he presents that points to consumers being unsatisfied with their choices of density, though those sorts of surveys are problematic because of the difference between consumers’ revealed preferences and their stated preferences.

    There are few or no regulations regarding density in much of Texas, for example, and low density the lifestyle of choice for most of the people in Texas cities.

    I presume you’re talking mostly about Houston, the so-called unzoned city. In that case, your statement that there are “few or no regulations regarding density” is false. As Michael Lewyn explains:

    Like other cities’ zoning codes, Houston’s municipal code creates auto dependency by artificially spreading out the population. Until 1999, the city required all single-family houses to gobble up 5,000 square feet of land. Although this limit is less rigid than minimum lot sizes in most suburbs, the city’s statute nevertheless insures that many residents will be unable to live within walking distance of a bus stop, which in turn means that those residents will be completely dependent on their cars. In 1999, the City Council partially deregulated density in neighborhoods closer to downtown. But since 98% of the city’s housing was built before 1999, this change in the law is of little importance.

    Houston’s parking regulations also create automobile dependency by encouraging driving and discouraging walking. Under Houston’s city code, virtually every structure in Houston must supply plenty of parking. For example, apartment buildings must have even more parking spaces than residents; landlords must supply 1.25 parking spaces for each efficiency apartment and 1.33 parking spaces for every bedroom. Offices, supermarkets, and other businesses are subject to similar restrictions. Such parking regulations discourage walking by forcing pedestrians to navigate through massive parking lots (and to dodge the vehicles driving them) to reach shops or jobs. And where walking is uncomfortable, most people will drive. In addition, minimum parking requirements, by taking land for parking that could have been used for housing or businesses, also reduce density, thus making the city less compact and more auto-dependent.

    Parking regulations, as explained by Donald Shoup in his book The High Cost of Free Parking are almost as important (if not more important) than zoning regulations in determining the density at which a developer can feasibly build.

    Density isn’t the solution.

    I’ll definitely agree with you that mandatory density isn’t the solution. However, liberalizing rules about how densely Americans can build (especially in cities and inner-suburbs) most definitely is part of the solution.

  5. MarketUrbanism says

    November 13, 2008 at 12:09 am

    The idea, however, that there is some regulatory conspiracy forcing low-density development and that higher densities would “more profitable” (how can it be more profitable when it isn’t profitable today?) is a fantasy.

    Randal, the “conspiracy forcing low-density development” is no fantasy – it’s called “zoning”. However, zoning is no smoke-filled-room “conspiracy”. It’s an out-in-the-open, restriction of land use, which was born through the progressive movement and approved by the Supreme Court.

    Perhaps not in isolated parts of Texas, but in most places zoning restrictions limit the density of new development with regards to FAR, units per acre, setbacks, etc. Without these limits, denser projects would be more profitable. Otherwise, zoning limits wouldn’t be “restrictions”, but mere features. I don’t know how you could say higher densities aren’t more profitable, if they must be restricted, thus hurting otherwise profitable development. As a developer, I rarely (probably never have, actually) encounter a project where it’s highest-and-best economical use is as-of-right.

    Density isn’t the solution. Opening up transit systems to competition and encourage private operators to find innovative ways to provide transit will work better.

    Why can’t density be the solution? Certainly if it is restricted now, liberalizing land use would allow a more natural, and often denser land use pattern to emerge. Legalizing density allows market demand to be better accommodated in well-located developments.

    However, I do agree about opening transit (and highways) to competitive forces, and applaud efforts to introduce market mechanisms to the otherwise socialist, taxpayer-funded systems.

  6. MarketUrbanism says

    November 13, 2008 at 12:09 am

    The idea, however, that there is some regulatory conspiracy forcing low-density development and that higher densities would “more profitable” (how can it be more profitable when it isn’t profitable today?) is a fantasy.

    Randal, the “conspiracy forcing low-density development” is no fantasy – it’s called “zoning”. However, zoning is no smoke-filled-room “conspiracy”. It’s an out-in-the-open, restriction of land use, which was born through the progressive movement and approved by the Supreme Court.

    Perhaps not in isolated parts of Texas, but in most places zoning restrictions limit the density of new development with regards to FAR, units per acre, setbacks, etc. Without these limits, denser projects would be more profitable. Otherwise, zoning limits wouldn’t be “restrictions”, but mere features. I don’t know how you could say higher densities aren’t more profitable, if they must be restricted, thus hurting otherwise profitable development. As a developer, I rarely (probably never have, actually) encounter a project where it’s highest-and-best economical use is as-of-right.

    Density isn’t the solution. Opening up transit systems to competition and encourage private operators to find innovative ways to provide transit will work better.

    Why can’t density be the solution? Certainly if it is restricted now, liberalizing land use would allow a more natural, and often denser land use pattern to emerge. Legalizing density allows market demand to be better accommodated in well-located developments.

    However, I do agree about opening transit (and highways) to competitive forces, and applaud efforts to introduce market mechanisms to the otherwise socialist, taxpayer-funded systems.

  7. MarketUrbanism says

    November 13, 2008 at 12:09 am

    The idea, however, that there is some regulatory conspiracy forcing low-density development and that higher densities would “more profitable” (how can it be more profitable when it isn’t profitable today?) is a fantasy.

    Randal, the “conspiracy forcing low-density development” is no fantasy – it’s called “zoning”. However, zoning is no smoke-filled-room “conspiracy”. It’s an out-in-the-open, restriction of land use, which was born through the progressive movement and approved by the Supreme Court.

    Perhaps not in isolated parts of Texas, but in most places zoning restrictions limit the density of new development with regards to FAR, units per acre, setbacks, etc. Without these limits, denser projects would be more profitable. Otherwise, zoning limits wouldn’t be “restrictions”, but mere features. I don’t know how you could say higher densities aren’t more profitable, if they must be restricted, thus hurting otherwise profitable development. As a developer, I rarely (probably never have, actually) encounter a project where it’s highest-and-best economical use is as-of-right.

    Density isn’t the solution. Opening up transit systems to competition and encourage private operators to find innovative ways to provide transit will work better.

    Why can’t density be the solution? Certainly if it is restricted now, liberalizing land use would allow a more natural, and often denser land use pattern to emerge. Legalizing density allows market demand to be better accommodated in well-located developments.

    However, I do agree about opening transit (and highways) to competitive forces, and applaud efforts to introduce market mechanisms to the otherwise socialist, taxpayer-funded systems.

  8. Market Urbanism says

    November 13, 2008 at 12:09 am

    The idea, however, that there is some regulatory conspiracy forcing low-density development and that higher densities would “more profitable” (how can it be more profitable when it isn’t profitable today?) is a fantasy.

    Randall, the “conspiracy forcing low-density development” is no fantasy – it’s called “zoning”. However, zoning is no smoke-filled-room “conspiracy”. It’s an out-in-the-open, restriction of land use, which was born through the progressive movement and approved by the Supreme Court.

    Perhaps not in isolated parts of Texas, but in most places zoning restrictions limit the density of new development with regards to FAR, units per acre, setbacks, etc. Without these limits, denser projects would be more profitable. Otherwise, zoning limits wouldn’t be “restrictions”, but mere features. I don’t know how you could say higher densities aren’t more profitable, if they must be restricted, thus hurting otherwise profitable development. As a developer, I rarely (probably never have, actually) encounter a project where it’s highest-and-best economical use is as-of-right.

    Density isn’t the solution. Opening up transit systems to competition and encourage private operators to find innovative ways to provide transit will work better.

    Why can’t density be the solution? Certainly if it is restricted now, liberalizing land use would allow a more natural, and often denser land use pattern to emerge. Legalizing density allows market demand to be better accommodated in well-located developments.

    However, I do agree about opening transit (and highways) to competitive forces, and applaud efforts to introduce market mechanisms to the otherwise socialist, taxpayer-funded systems.

  9. Eric says

    November 17, 2008 at 2:02 pm

    Our hwy vs. transit arguments are based on yesterday’s facts and methods…Who’s studying what’s going on now? The best argument for rail may be in fact cooking up in Houston as we speak.

    In Charlotte, the Road brigade were laughed out of town. To good measure. Close to 50% of all new red dirt on the ground three miles from downtown is 1/2 mile from the South Corridor light rail. (Check it out on Google Earth!) $1/2 billion of public investment just produced $2.1 billion (mostly in high density brownfield redevelopment). And that’s the short term return on the South Corridor. Then there’s also the handy fact that in one year of operation, we obliterated our projected ridership numbers…and are approaching the 2030 projections. Shows you just how out of date our science is.

    Randal, you have to base your diagnoses and solutions on what is going on NOW.

  10. Eric says

    November 17, 2008 at 2:02 pm

    Our hwy vs. transit arguments are based on yesterday’s facts and methods…Who’s studying what’s going on now? The best argument for rail may be in fact cooking up in Houston as we speak.

    In Charlotte, the Road brigade were laughed out of town. To good measure. Close to 50% of all new red dirt on the ground three miles from downtown is 1/2 mile from the South Corridor light rail. (Check it out on Google Earth!) $1/2 billion of public investment just produced $2.1 billion (mostly in high density brownfield redevelopment). And that’s the short term return on the South Corridor. Then there’s also the handy fact that in one year of operation, we obliterated our projected ridership numbers…and are approaching the 2030 projections. Shows you just how out of date our science is.

    Randal, you have to base your diagnoses and solutions on what is going on NOW.

  11. Tushar says

    January 15, 2009 at 5:11 pm

    IS the point then that a private solution will probably not emerge if we just auctioned off all the land the roads use (as opposed to only the roads)? That prices will not signal scarcity efficiently? That entrepreneurs will not use these price signals for innovation
    and serving transportation needs especially using current technology?

    If so, that should be a tough case to argue using established economic theory.

  12. Tushar says

    January 15, 2009 at 5:11 pm

    IS the point then that a private solution will probably not emerge if we just auctioned off all the land the roads use (as opposed to only the roads)? That prices will not signal scarcity efficiently? That entrepreneurs will not use these price signals for innovation
    and serving transportation needs especially using current technology?

    If so, that should be a tough case to argue using established economic theory.

  13. Tushar says

    January 15, 2009 at 5:11 pm

    IS the point then that a private solution will probably not emerge if we just auctioned off all the land the roads use (as opposed to only the roads)? That prices will not signal scarcity efficiently? That entrepreneurs will not use these price signals for innovation
    and serving transportation needs especially using current technology?

    If so, that should be a tough case to argue using established economic theory.

  14. Stephen Smith says

    January 15, 2009 at 5:28 pm

    Yes, that’s my point. The reason being that even if the roads are privatized, the land besides them is still not properly privatized – density restrictions (in the form of zoning, minimum parking regulations, and other ad hoc land use regulations) still encumber the land, preventing it from being used most productively. And, by extension, prevent the land underneath the roads from being used most efficiently.

    How is this at odds with established economic theory?

  15. Rationalitate says

    January 15, 2009 at 5:28 pm

    Yes, that’s my point. The reason being that even if the roads are privatized, the land besides them is still not properly privatized – density restrictions (in the form of zoning, minimum parking regulations, and other ad hoc land use regulations) still encumber the land, preventing it from being used most productively. And, by extension, prevent the land underneath the roads from being used most efficiently.

    How is this at odds with established economic theory?

  16. Rationalitate says

    January 15, 2009 at 5:28 pm

    Yes, that’s my point. The reason being that even if the roads are privatized, the land besides them is still not properly privatized – density restrictions (in the form of zoning, minimum parking regulations, and other ad hoc land use regulations) still encumber the land, preventing it from being used most productively. And, by extension, prevent the land underneath the roads from being used most efficiently.

    How is this at odds with established economic theory?

  17. Anonymous says

    October 5, 2009 at 5:31 am

    As most sink units are blind date uncensored placed in front of the kitchen window fabrics can easily be splashed with water causing mildew and unsightly stains. Venetian blinds are very easy to keep clean, another reason for their practicality for use in a kitchen.

Listen in

  • Abundance
  • Conversations with Tyler
  • Densely Speaking
  • Ideas of India
  • Order Without Design
  • UCLA Housing Voice
  • Yeoman

Connect With Us

  • Email
  • Facebook
  • Linkedin
  • RSS
  • Twitter

Market Sites Urbanists should check out

  • Arpitrage
  • Cafe Hayek
  • Center for Building in North America blog
  • Construction Physics
  • Conversable Economist
  • Environmental and Urban Economics | Matt Kahn
  • Erdmann Housing Tracker
  • Foundation for Economic Education
  • Marginal Revolution
  • Marginal Revolution University
  • Parafin
  • Propmodo
  • Rent Free
  • Time & Space
  • Urbanomics

Urbanism Sites capitalists should check out

  • Caos Planejado
  • City Density
  • Cornerstone
  • Granola Shotgun
  • Important Readings in Urbanism
  • Kartografia Ekstremalna
  • Metropolitan Abundance Project
  • Pedestrian Observations
  • Planetizen
  • Reinventing Parking
  • Skynomics Blog
  • StreetsBlog USA
  • Strong Towns
  • The Corner Side Yard | Pete Saunders
  • YIMBY Alliance

Meta

  • Log in
  • Entries RSS
  • Comments RSS
  • WordPress.org

Copyright © 2025 Market Urbanism